Journal of Business Accounting and Finance Perspectives

(ISSN: 2603-7475) Open Access Journal
Rss Feed:

Journal of Business Accounting and Finance Perspectives is no longer published on JAMS (the publishing platform provided by MDPI) as of 10.07.2021. The articles published until that date are archived at jbafp.archive.jams.pub by courtesy of JAMS.

J_Bus_Account_Financ_Perspect 2020, 3(1), 10; doi:10.26870/jbafp.2020.03.010

Article
Investment Diversification and Optimal Cultural Background
Kafka I. Kyriaki, Valsamis G. Dionysis and Panagiotis E. Petrakis *
Department of Economics, National and Kapodistrian University of Athens, 5 Stadiou Street, 10562 Athens, Greece; kkafka@econ.uoa.gr (K.I.K.); dvalsamis@econ.uoa.gr (V.G.D.)
*
Corresponding author: ppetrak@econ.uoa.gr
How to cite: Kafka I. Kyriaki, Valsamis G. Dionysis, Panagiotis E. Petrakis. Investment Diversification and Optimal Cultural Background. J. Bus. Account. Financ. Perspect., 2020, 3(1): 10; doi:10.26870/jbafp.2020.03.010.
Received: 27 August 2019 / Accepted: 13 February 2020 / Published: 14 February 2020

Abstract

:
Investment diversification is a prerequisite for dynamic growth performance. It is intuitively accepted that cultural background affects investment behavior and investment decision making, but does cultural change affect investment diversification? This paper assesses whether cultural background shapes growth performance through investment diversification. Empirical analysis was conducted using decade-level data for a sample of 33 OECD countries over the 30-year period from 1981 to 2010. Using fixed effects estimation, different intercepts across countries, and decade time dummies, the analysis shows that societies that are closer to the optimal cultural background achieve better investment diversification behavior. The article thus contributes to the long-standing debate on the cultural roots of growth.
Keywords:
culture; cultural change; diversification; investment; panel data

1. Introduction

The scope of cultural background’s effect on economic development and growth is a pertinent issue in economics (Schumpeter, 1934), sociology (Weber, 1930), and psychology (McClelland, 1961). The cultural characteristics of societies are psychosocial stereotypes that have developed over time. These stereotypes are human constructs that existed long before the emergence of today’s transactions and institutions. Economic development is affected by traits that have been transmitted from generation to generation through fundamental factors that are rooted in history (Spolaore and Wacziarg, 2013). These traits define the cultural backgrounds of societies.
Given the relationship between cultural background and investment behavior, and given the cultural changes that are embodied in social behavior and economic decisions, we address the following question: Does cultural change affect investment diversification? Diversification is important for the economy. Diversification of investment and production is essential for economic growth. This statement has been extensively analyzed in the economic literature. The Nobel laureate Simon Kuznets (1971) defined a country’s economic growth as a long-term rise in capacity to supply increasingly diverse economic goods to the population. This definition is supported by the views of Grossman and Helpman (1992), who claim that for an economy to grow, it must produce an increasing quantity, quality, and variety of goods and services.
This paper explores the relationship between cultural background and investment behavior by focusing on investment diversification. Empirical evidence is provided through the analysis of three decades of data for a sample of 33 OECD countries. The paper shows how changes in the cultural background of societies between 1980 and 2010 have influenced investment diversification behavior. Societies that are characterized by optimal cultural values—that is, societies that are close to the optimal cultural background—achieve investment diversification behavior, unlike societies that have low scores in their cultural values. Although several studies have examined the impact of cultural background on economic outcomes and investment behavior, no study has linked cultural background to investment diversification behavior. Most empirical studies that have used cross-country data to investigate the effects of cultural background on economic outcomes (Alesina and Giuliano, 2015; Gorodonichencko and Roland, 2010, 2015; Guiso et al., 2006) have considered cultural traits as enduring qualities. In this study, a broad study period was considered. Panel data on cultural background and investment diversification over the past three decades were used.
We contribute to the literature by adopting a broad definition of cultural background while considering specific cultural traits. In addition, by determining differences in the performance of societies with optimal cultural characteristics and the performance of other societies, we also contribute to the literature that explores cultural effects on economic outcomes. This last contribution relates to the implications of this study. Linking the investment diversification behavior to the cultural background of societies can highlight critical issues regarding economies’ growth potential, thereby explaining the presence of stagnated growth prototypes.
This article has the following structure: Section 2 reviews the literature discussing the effects of cultural background on investment behavior. Section 3 describes the data and method that were used for the empirical analysis. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Lastly, Section 5 offers a discussion and conclusions.

2. Literature Review

The terms “culture” and “cultural background” reflect the behavior of the individual. This behavior is influenced by others through teaching, imitation, and other forms of social transmission. Culture comprises all beliefs, preferences, skills, values, stereotypes, and norms that characterize the members of a society and differentiate them from members of other societies. The way that an individual behaves, perceives, and reacts depends on the architecture of the human mind and body, which is shaped over millennia by organic evolution. Therefore, culture can be considered an aspect of human biology, as well as an important factor in shaping the way people think and function (Boyd and Richerson, 2005). Hofstede (2001) describes culture as “the collective programming of the mind,” whereas Inglehart (1997) refers to it as a “system of attitudes, values and knowledge that is widely shared within a society and is transmitted from generation to generation.”
But does cultural background have any systematic influence on economic decision making? This question is at the heart of research into the effects of culture on economic outcomes. In this paper, we focus on investment decisions. An affirmative answer to this question would explain why some countries are unable to achieve a pro-growth prototype (Petrakis et al., 2016) because it is widely accepted that cultural background changes gradually and therefore influences the investment structure.
Certain theorists support the thesis that cultural background affects investment decisions and behavior (Anderson et al., 2011; Beckmann et al., 2008; Griblatt and Keloharjut, 2001; Levinson and Peng, 2007). Anderson et al. (2011) conclude that culture affects investor behavior directly rather than though indirect channels such as legal and regulatory frameworks. Cultural background has also been found to affect investment decisions in financial markets (Guiso et al., 2007; Hernandez and Cervantes, 2012), economic decision making, judgments of financial value and property ownership (Levinson and Peng, 2007), earnings-management decisions in firms (Cetenak et al., 2017), and the importance of stock markets (Jong and Semenov, 2002).
Be it directly or indirectly, culture influences the outcome of economic procedures. The views of the people and the grid of values influence the organization and operation of institutions, and hence the way available resources within society are channeled. The converse is also true: Though indirectly, the economic outcome and institutions can influence the way individuals think and therefore their cultural background (Petrakis, 2014).
Numerous studies have quantified the effects of cultural background. These studies provide data for many countries (Hofstede, 2001; House et al., 2004; McClelland, 1961). These studies’ results show that culture can have specific, significant effects on economic growth (Granato et al., 1996; Marini, 2004; Minkov and Blagoev, 2009; Triandis, 1995).
Beckmann et al. (2008) report that differences in cultural background are useful for understanding country differences that cannot be interpreted solely using economic logic. Drawing on Hofstede’s (2001) four cultural dimensions, Beckmann et al. (2008) reported several interesting findings: more individualistic societies tend to have less herding behavior; greater power distance leads to older and less-experienced managers in the upper hierarchy; masculinity takes men to top positions and gives them higher volumes of assets under their personal responsibility; and uncertainty avoidance relates to higher safety margins against tracking error allowed and greater research effort.
Investigating how cultural background affects economic decision making, Levinson and Peng (2007) found dramatic cultural differences and observed the influence of variables such as framing, morality, and group membership. The decision-making process depends greatly on cultural background (Cetenak et al., 2017). Executives’ financial decisions vary from society to society because of cultural differences.
Cultural background also affects individuals’ cognitive and emotional capacity in terms of investment behavior (Statman, 2008). Inhabitants of low-income countries have high expectations with regard to their current income. They assign greater risk to a possible change in their lives than do individuals in collectivistic countries, where people take more risks because their in-groups provide downside protection and because trusting people are willing to take more risk.
Typical examples of the cultural background’s influence on the development of traditional investments are town planning, transport, and the environment (Petrakis, 2014). A society that strongly favors the present over the future would struggle to implement town planning and environmental planning schemes to serve the interests of future generations. In such societies, towns and infrastructure are not planned. If they are, they have a tight development schedule because of a reliance on short-term profit maximization. However, town planning is by nature a serious requirement for economic structures. It dramatically influences the way economies grow. Hence, if investments in traditional infrastructure assets (e.g., ports and airports) are poorly executed and lack foresight, they can easily lose value and prove difficult to replace.
High-trust nations tend to reduce transaction costs, promote economic efficiency, offer incentives for large-scale investment, and, ultimately, boost economic development. Risk-averse societies tend to have lower growth perspectives because investment initiatives are constrained (Petrakis, 2014).
Griblatt and Keloharjut (2001) argue that investors simultaneously prefer nearby, same-language, and same-culture firms. Considerable evidence suggests an inverse link between the magnitude of these effects of investment behavior and investment complexity.
Jong and Semenov (2002) examined how factors that determine differences in stock market activity in different societies correlate with the standards and values of each society. These standards and values reflect cultural dimensions. Jong and Semenov concluded that societies with low uncertainty avoidance are particularly important for stock markets. Such societies tolerate uncertainty and reward competition (high score of masculinity).
Anderson et al. (2011) argue that intercultural attitudes help explain home bias and diversification in foreign equities. They report that investment schemes that originate in countries with high uncertainty avoidance have greater home bias and less diversification in foreign holdings. In addition, portfolios from countries with high levels of masculinity and long-term orientation have lower home bias levels, while portfolios from countries with high masculinity levels are more diversified abroad. They conclude that cultural background affects the behavior of investors directly—not only indirectly through channels such as the legal and regulatory framework.
Zhan (2012) examined the impact of national culture on herding behavior in international financial markets. Zhan also examined the relationships between culture and investment behavior and between culture and overall market volatility. Zhan observed that societies with lower levels of individualism are more likely to have a higher number of synchronized stock price movements. In addition, correlation between stock price movements increases stock market volatility, while highly individualistic behaviors reduce the number of synchronized stock price movements (i.e., lower stock market volatility) (Guiso et al., 2007).
Although there are no similar empirical studies, this study examined whether the effect of cultural background on decision making and investment behavior determines investment diversification. A diversified economy receives income from several directly unrelated sources (Shayah, 2015). If a country’s income depends on the production of just one product, fluctuations in the price of that product can lead to fluctuations in the standard of living. Imbs and Wacziarg (2003) identified a pattern of sector diversification throughout development. Countries first diversify, spreading economic activity across sectors. However, late in the development process, countries start specializing again. So, sectoral diversification first increases, but beyond a certain level of per capita income, the sector distribution of economic activity starts to shrink.
Furthermore, economic growth and structural change depend on the types of products that are traded (Hausmann and Klinger, 2006; Hwang, 2006). Thus, export diversification allows an economy to progress toward the production and exportation of sophisticated products that may contribute to sustainable economic development, the achievement of macroeconomic objectives, satisfactory balance of payments, stable export revenues, and high rates of employment and redistribution of income. Romer (1990) therefore identifies diversification as an input factor that improves the efficiency of other factors of production. Similarly, Acemoglu and Zilibotti (1997) claim that diversification may increase income by increasing the potential to spread investment risks over a wider portfolio.
Osakwe (2007) reports a more specific effect of product diversification, linking diversification to risk. Osakwe found that policymakers in developing countries seek to diversify their production and export structures to reduce vulnerability to external shocks. This finding is consistent with those of Ramey and Ramey (1995), who report that more diversified economies are less volatile in terms of outputs and that lower output volatility is associated with greater economic growth. A diversification strategy is often employed by owner-managers to reduce employment- and reputation-related risks. Such strategies can decrease the financial risk of firms by allowing firms to diversify into unrelated activities (Amihud and Lev, 1981). Furthermore, intra-industry product diversification leads to a trade-off between the potential risks of exceeding the reasonable capacity to offer diverse products and the possible demand externalities that are generated by offering a broad range of products (Kang et al., 2010). Ballivian and Sickles (1994) analyzed the relationship between risk-avoidance behavior and economic jointness in multioutput technology, noting that diversification in production can have several explanations, including jointness, cost complementarities, and risk avoidance.
Systematic risk can be affected by diversification. Bettis and Mahajan (1985) and Montgomery and Singh (1984) have linked diversification strategies to the level of systematic risk in terms of the systematic risk beta (taken as a proxy for market risk). They conclude that diversification increases corporate returns and reduces systematic risk. Lubatkin and Chatterjee (1994) present two opposite effects of systematic risk that nullify one another. While diversification reduces systematic risk, it also increases leverage, which tends to increase systematic risk. Lubatkin and Chatterjee (1994) also argue that firms can significantly minimize risk by diversifying into similar businesses rather than identical or very different businesses.
Therefore, the cultural characteristics of societies affect the way in which its members allocate available resources to specific investments. Thus, a portfolio of investment choices emerges in each society with particular characteristics, forming a pro-growth or stagnated growth prototype (Petrakis et al., 2016).

3. Method and Data Description

Our dataset consisted of an unbalanced panel of decade-level data for the OECD countries over the period 1980 to 2010. The final sample and study period were determined by data availability. Data on investment by asset were gathered from the OECD database. Cultural variables were gathered from Bützer et al.’s (2013) dataset. We used an unbalanced panel of 33 countries1 and data from three decades for the analysis.
To examine the effects of culture on investment diversification behavior, we first employed the following baseline estimation equation:
D i v e r s i f i c a t i o n i t = a i + β   C u l t u r a l I n d e x i t +   γ   Z i t + λ t + u i t ,
where i denotes the country and t the decade (tmax = 3). For each country, the dependent variable, Diversificationit, denotes the sum of the differences (with respect to a benchmark of countries) in terms of investment in six asset types. For each country, CulturalIndexit denotes the sum of differences (with respect to a benchmark of countries) in terms of six cultural variables. Zit is a vector of macroeconomic control variables. αi is a set of country-specific fixed effects that capture the influence of unobserved country-specific heterogeneity. Finally, time dummies, λt, for each decade in the sample control for decade-specific effects.
Equation (1) was analyzed using panel data estimation. Fixed effects estimation was used. Fixed effects estimation allows for individual heterogeneity using different intercepts across countries. Estimation can be performed using ordinary least squares. We employed cluster-robust estimation for standard errors to control for serial correlation and heteroskedasticity. We included decade time dummies to incorporate time-specific effects that were common to all countries in our sample.
Following previous studies of the impact of culture on the macroeconomy (Bjornskov and Meon, 2015; Butzer et al., 2013) and studies of the relationship between institutions and diversification (Boschma and Capone, 2015; Hare, 2008), we included institutional variables as controls to isolate their effect on diversification. Restricted by data availability, we included the level of government expenditure (gov), the quality of government as a measure of institutional quality (qog), and confidence in national institutions (conf). The control variables were sourced from Bützer et al.’s (2013) dataset.
As a benchmark for investment diversification, we used investment by asset from the OECD database. These data reflect investment in each asset type as a percentage of gross fixed capital formation. We included the following asset types in our analysis: dwellings (excluding land), other buildings and structures (roads, bridges, airfields, dams, etc.), transport equipment (ships, trains, aircraft, etc.), other machinery and equipment (Ιnformation and Communication Technology (ICT) equipment, office machinery and hardware, weapons systems, etc.), cultivated assets (managed forests, livestock raised for milk production, etc.), and intellectual property products (intangible fixed assets such as R&D, mineral exploration, software and databases, and literary and artistic originals).
We then calculated an investment diversification index based on the data described above. This index was calculated as the difference between each country and a benchmark (i.e., the five countries with the highest GDP growth rate over the last three decades). We assumed that countries that had achieved the highest GDP growth rates over the last three decades would have also achieved good investment diversification performance and should therefore be regarded as a benchmark for other economies in terms of economic performance. To determine which countries were used for this investment diversification benchmark, we checked which countries had the highest GDP growth rates in each year over the last three decades. We summed the classification for each country each year. The countries with the lowest sum were classified in the top positions over the study period. We then took the average investment per asset type for the countries in the top five positions. These averages provided our benchmark. The sum of differences between each country’s investment in each asset type and the benchmark countries’ investment in each asset type yielded the investment diversification index. The smaller the price of the index, the smaller the difference of a country from the benchmark countries, and the better the diversification performance of that country.
We also developed an index for cultural values. The cultural dataset was gathered from Bützer et al. (2013). This dataset contained decade-level data for cultural variables. The cultural variables in Bützer et al.’s (2013) dataset were created using survey data from the World Values Survey (WVS) and the European Values Study (EVS). These data were aggregated to decade-level data, thereby providing observations over three decades (1980s, 1990s, and 2000s) for each country. The variables were interpersonal trust, control of life, work ethic, obedience, competition affinity, honesty, and propensity to save (for detailed definitions, see Bützer et al., 2013). We used the maximum value for each of the six cultural variables (obedience and competition affinity were measured on a reversed scale) as a benchmark. As we did for the investment diversification index, we used the sum of differences between each country’s score for each cultural variable and the benchmark score to define the cultural index. The smaller the score of the index, the smaller the difference between the country score and the benchmark score, and the better the cultural background of that country.
We classified our dataset based on each country’s cultural index score. We grouped countries depending on whether their cultural index scores lay above or below the median of the cultural index for each decade. We studied the correlations between the diversification index and the cultural index for countries whose median cultural index values were above or below the median. We then studied the effects of cultural background on investment diversification based on the following two equations, which follow the same estimation approach as in Equation (1):
D i v   I n d e x   a b o v e i t = a i + β   C u l t   I n d e x   a b o v e   i t +   γ   Z i t + λ t + u i t ,
D i v   I n d e x   b e l o w j t = a i + β   C u l t   I n d e x   b e l o w   j t +   γ   Z j t + λ t + u j t ,
where i denotes the countries above the median for Equation (2), j the countries below the median for Equation (3), and t the decade (tmax = 3). DivIndexaboveit and DivIndexbelowit reflect the diversification index for countries whose scores lay above and below the median of the cultural index, respectively. Similarly, CultIndexaboveit and CultIndexbelowit reflect the cultural index for countries whose scores lay above and below the median of the cultural index, respectively. As in Equation (1), Zit is a vector of macroeconomic control variables, αi is a set of country-specific fixed effects that capture the influence of unobserved country-specific heterogeneity, and λt are time dummies that control for decade-specific effects. Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics of the variables in the analysis.

4. Empirical Results

The five countries with the highest GDP growth rates over the last three decades were Korea, Ireland, Israel, Australia, and Poland (Table A1 in the Appendix A classifies the countries for each year and shows the average score for the entire period of 1981 to 2010). These countries were taken as the benchmark countries in our analysis. The diversification index was built by calculating each country’s difference from this benchmark and summing these differences for each asset type.
The best scores for the cultural index were attained by the Czech Republic in competition affinity in the second decade, Denmark in trust in the third decade, Japan in obedience in the third decade, Korea in propensity to save in third decade, Mexico in control of life in the third decade, Norway in work ethic in the third decade, and Sweden in honesty in the first decade (Table A2 in the Appendix A shows the best scores for each cultural variable). These scores were taken as the benchmark scores in our analysis to represent an optimal cultural background. For each country and for each decade, the cultural index was built by calculating each country’s difference from this benchmark and summing these differences.
The correlation between the diversification index and cultural index was 0.006. After dividing the sample into above- and below-median countries in terms of the cultural index scores for each decade, we obtained the correlations in Table 2.
The correlations improved for countries that were classified below the median of the cultural index in decades 2 (correlation 0.429) and 3 (correlation 0.276). The countries with below-median scores had smaller differences from the benchmark scores.
Table 3 shows the results of the fixed effects estimation of Equations (1)–(3). Fixed effects estimation allows for individual heterogeneity using different intercepts across countries. It also enables estimation using ordinary least squares.
The results do not imply a significant relationship between the cultural index and the diversification index (regression 1 in Table 3). After grouping the countries according to whether their cultural index scores lay above or below the median, we observed that for above-median countries, there was no significant relationship between culture and investment diversification (regression 2 in Table 3). However, regression 3 in Table 3 indicates a positively significant relationship between culture and investment diversification for countries whose cultural index scores lay below the median. Countries that were closer to the benchmark of the seven cultural variables seemed to achieve better investment diversification.
Next, we drew on the literature to explore the sensitivity of our results regarding the relationship between culture and investment diversification and to control for any potential indirect effect—through the society’s macroeconomic and institutional environment—of culture on investment diversification. To do so, we included additional control variables and employed alternative specifications of Equation (3). The results in Table 3 show that the positive effect of cultural background on investment diversification remained stable and even strengthened when we used control variables in our analysis. Regression 4 in Table 3 shows the baseline specification including control variables. The positive effect of culture on investment diversification was intensified. In regression 4, we observed the greatest impact of cultural background on investment diversification.

5. Discussion and Conclusions

Countries have varying levels of investment diversification because of different cultural backgrounds. A society’s grid of values either encourages or discourages investment diversification behavior. The analysis showed that cultural background change that took place over the last three decades led to changes in the investment behavior of societies—specifically, changes in the investment diversification of economies.
We used an unbalanced panel of decade-level data for 33 OECD countries over the period 1981 to 2010 to explore the relationship between cultural change and investment diversification. Using fixed effects estimation, different intercepts across countries, and decade time dummies, we showed that societies that are closer to the optimal cultural background achieve better investment diversification. This positive effect of cultural background on investment diversification remains stable across different control variables and alternative specifications.
Our findings are important for policymakers, who need to understand the investment diversification of their economies. By understanding the effects of cultural background on investment diversification, policymakers will be better equipped to confront issues regarding economic performance because diversification of investment is essential for economic growth. Governments should establish processes to improve cultural values and reduce cultural barriers. For example, appropriate investment in human capital through education is necessary.
One limitation of the empirical analysis is the assumption that countries that had a strong GDP growth rate also had strong investment diversification. This assumption reflected an attempt to calculate a diversification index for the study period. A further limitation is that the exact factors that led to cultural background change cannot be derived, nor can the factors that explain how or in which direction the cultural background changed in the last three decades.
Future research should focus on the effects of cultural change on investment diversification over an extended period. For example, future studies should use annual data. Improved data collection methods in the coming years would help researchers enhance research into cultural background changes and strengthen the validity of cultural data (Guiso et al., 2006).

Appendix A

Table A1. Classification of the countries in GDP growth rate (1981–2010).
Table A1. Classification of the countries in GDP growth rate (1981–2010).
Country198119821983198419851986198719881989199019911992199319941995199619971998199920002001200220032004200520062007200820092010Mean 1981–2010
Korea211111113113113283313311311101096414.6
Chile329287234531133129443113279115264113638.4
Ireland1412251624281321531541352121222373561632191910.7
Israel4141123774182545272161915184323323887753510.9
Luxembourg201613832122272135182928733516102212141132924411.4
Poland292822811921201628281148654510142721961255211012.8
Australia820244518814919239611141115813301471217162412821713.3
USA13263288151518181961015161311128192816152013252923101515.0
Finland174615131714872527282416815641161318181921171019321215.0
Spain241515251810678111220282610232010710513112211151514143115.2
Iceland69271214322829212029151931101821412626161312212303215.4
New Zealand115233282519252422261933714253012201544132323142552016.3
Canada1027106622101223262518111317251719592312192315262815121116.5
Mexico12129132229242313867141232757248332921161813231320616.6
Norway1519554623292617115810999252529182224182229242073016.8
Sweden51312101914162222232226301412272613911241517152014192723217.4
Netherlands252414171613221110101314162119171696151731293025211710152717.7
Portugal98192926113642882329231814615232024333132322621132418.0
UK2710422912752124242412172122242320251214102819272528182318.6
Japan737921694669211831151932323132313020292833303125819.1
Slovak Rep.32323232323232323232323233453131730338535221126719.4
Austria22118272021252415971017241824292016282619272526221811162219.6
Hungary12620202926112727272927212220332214211676697203316292919.7
Greece282326241727291317291023292826211218222148273392224173320.1
Denmark2629111052826282017121961320232623242925282624183226222520.1
Estonia3131313131313131313131313232258116331121411433331620.5
Belgium2317222125242010191414162620222621271727301726212728201891420.7
Switzerland162521181223261911122125203030322824271825283127171613981320.8
France187172627201891215181522252729272119221923252429302722112120.8
Slovenia333333333333333333333333971116102241711914149864312820.9
Germany21221619211927171454172723283130282631213232333119211728922.3
Czech Rep.303030303030303030303030313333123331291310208104387211822.8
Italy19181814151517162016162225272430312928262227303230313130272623.7
Note: Chile and Luxembourg were excluded from the top five countries because of a lack of data for certain asset types.
Table A2. Best scores in each cultural variable.
Table A2. Best scores in each cultural variable.
CountryDecadeCompetition AffinityObedienceControl of LifeTrustWork EthicPropensity to SaveHonesty
Czech Rep.1991–2000−1.97
Germany2001–2010 70.16
Japan2001–2010 −2.34
Korea2001–2010 0.63
Mexico2001–2010 8.01
Norway2001–2010 1.93
Sweden1981–1990 1.77

References

  1. Acemoglu, D.; Zilibotti, F. Was Prometheus unbound by chance? Risk diversification and growth. Journal of Political Economy 1997, 105(4), 709–751. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Alesina, A.; Giuliano, P. Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature 2015, 53(4), 898–944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Amihud, Y.; Lev, B. Risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers. The Bell Journal of Economics 1981, 12(2), 605–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Anderson, C.; Fedenia, M.; Hirschey, M.; Skiba, H. Cultural influences on home bias and international diversification by institutional investors. Journal of Banking & Finance 2011, 35(4), 916–934. [Google Scholar]
  5. Ballivian, M. A.; Sickles, R. C. Product Diversification and Attitudes toward Risk in Agricultural Production. The Journal of Productivity Analysis 1994, 5, 271–286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Beckmann, D.; Menkhoff, L.; Suto, M. Does Culture Influence Asset Managers? Views and Behavior? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 2008, 67, 624–643. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Bettis, R. A.; Mahajan, V. Risk/return performance of diversified firms. Management Science 1985, 31, 785–799. [Google Scholar]
  8. Bjornskov, C.; Meon, P. G. The productivity of trust. World Development 2015, 70, 317–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Boschma, R.; Capone, G. Institutions and diversification: related versus unrelated diversification in a “varieties of capitalism” framework”. Research Policy 2015, 44, 1902–1914. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Boyd, R.; Richerson, P. J. The origin and evolution of cultures; Oxford University Press: Oxford, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  11. Bützer, S.; Jordan, C.; Stracca, L. Macroeconomic imbalances: A question of trust? (Working Paper Series 1584); European Central Bank: Frankfurt, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  12. Cetenak, E. H.; Cingoz, A.; Acar, E. The effect of national culture on corporate financial decisions. In Risk management, strategic thinking and leadership in the financial services industry. A proactive approach to strategic thinking; Dinçer, H., Hacioğlu, Ü., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: Basel, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  13. Gorodonichencko, Y.; Roland, G. Culture, institutions and the wealth of Nations; (NBER Working Paper No. 16368); NBER: Cambridge, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  14. Gorodonichencko, Y.; Roland, G. Culture, institutions and democratizations; (CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP10563); CEPR: Washington, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  15. Granato, J.; Inglehart, R.; Leblang, D. The effect of cultural values on economics development: Theory, hypotheses and some empirical tests. American Journal of Political Science 1996, 40, 607–631. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Griblatt, M.; Keloharjut, M. How distance, language, and culture influence stockholdings and trades. The Journal of Finance 2001, 56(3), 1053–1073. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Grossman, G. M.; Helpman, E. Innovation and growth in the global economy; MIT Press: Cambridge, 1992. [Google Scholar]
  18. Guiso, L.; Sapienza, P.; Zingales, L. Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives 2006, 20(2), 23–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Guiso, L.; Sapienza, P.; Zingales, L. Trusting the stock market; (ECGI—Finance Working Paper); ECGI: Brussels, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  20. Hare, P. G. Institutions and diversification of the economies in transition: Policy challenges; (CERT Discussion Papers 0804); Centre for Economic Reform and Transformation, Heriot Watt University: Edinburgh, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  21. Hausmann, R.; Klinger, B. Structural transformation and patterns of comparative advantage in the product space; (Working Paper Series rwp06-041); Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government: Cambridge, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  22. Hernandez, C.; Cervantes, M. Does culture affect in the financial decision making of rational man? Chinese vs. Anglo-Saxon Perspective. Global Review 2012, 6, 67–75. [Google Scholar]
  23. Hofstede, G. Culture’s consequences: Comparing values, behaviours, institutions and organizations across nations, 2nd ed.; Sage Publications: Beverly Hills, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  24. House, R. J.; Hanges, P. J.; Javidan, M.; Dorfman, P. W.; Gupta, V. Culture, leadership and organisations—The globe study of 62 societies; Sage Publications: Thousand Oaks, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  25. Hwang, J. Introduction of new goods, convergence and growth; Department of Economics, Harvard University, Mimeo: Cambridge, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  26. Imbs, J.; Wacziarg, R. Stages of Diversification. American Economic Review 2003, 93(1), 63–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Inglehart, R. The silent revolution: Changing values and political styles; Princeton University Press: Princeton, 1977. [Google Scholar]
  28. Jong, E.; Semenov, R. Cross-country differences in stock market development: A cultural view; (Research Report 02E40, EFA 2002 Berlin Meetings); University of Groningen, Research School “Systems, Organization and Management”: Groningen, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  29. Kang, K. H.; Lee, S.; Huh, C. Impacts of positive and negative corporate social responsibility activities on company performance in the hospitality industry. International Journal of Hospitality Management 2010, 29(1), 72–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Kuznets, S. Modern Economic Growth: Findings and Reflections. Prize Lecture, Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel. 11 December 1971. [Google Scholar]
  31. Levinson, J.; Peng, K. Valuing cultural differences in behavioral economics. The ICFAI Journal of Behavioral Finance 2007, 4(1), 32–47. [Google Scholar]
  32. Lubatkin, M.; Chatterjee, S. Extending modern portfolio theory into the domain of corporate diversification: Does it apply? Academy of Management Journal 1994, 37, 109–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Marini, M. Cultural evolution and economic growth: A theoretical hypothesis with some empirical evidence. The Journal of Socio-Economics 2004, 33, 765–784. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. McClelland, D. C. The achieving society; Van Nostrand: Princeton, 1961. [Google Scholar]
  35. Minkov, M.; Blagoev, V. Cultural values predict subsequent economic growth. International Journal of Cross-Cultural Management 2009, 9(1), 5–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Montgomery, C. A.; Singh, H. Diversification strategy and systematic risk. Straiegic Marzagenzent Jourriul 1984, 5(2), 181–191. [Google Scholar]
  37. Osakwe, P. N. Foreign aid, resources and export diversification in Africa: A new test of existing theories; (Work in Progress No. 61); United Nations Economic Commission for Africa, African Trade Policy Centre: Addis Ababa, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  38. Petrakis, P. E. Culture, growth and economic policy; from the question to exploration; Springer: New York and Heidelberg, 2014; ISBN 978-3-642-41439-8. [Google Scholar]
  39. Petrakis, P. E.; Kostis, P. C.; Kafka, I. K. Secular stagnation, faltering innovation, and high uncertainty: New-era entrepreneurship appraisal using knowledge-based thinking. Journal of Business Research 2016, 69(5), 1909–1913. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Ramey, G.; Ramey, V. A. Cross-country evidence on the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review 1995, 85(5), 1138–1151. [Google Scholar]
  41. Romer, P. M. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 1990, 98(5), S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Schumpeter, J. A. The theory of economic development; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, 1934. [Google Scholar]
  43. Shayah, M. H. Economic diversification by boosting non-oil exports. Journal of Economics, Business and Management 2015, 3(7), 735–738. [Google Scholar]
  44. Spolaore, E.; Wacziarg, R. How deep are the roots of economic development? Journal of Economic Literature 2013, 51(2), 1–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Statman, M. Countries and Culture in Behavioral Finance. Paper presented at the Wealth Management 2008 Conference, Atlanta, GA, USA, April 8–9; 2008. [Google Scholar]
  46. Triandis, H. C. Individualism and collectivism; Westview Press: Boulder, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  47. Weber, M. The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism; Unwin Hyman: London, 1930. [Google Scholar]
  48. Zhan, F. Individualism, Synchronized Stock Price Movements, and Stock Market Volatility. Paper presented at the 2013 Applied Finance Conference, St. John’s University, New York City, NY, USA, May 17; 2012. [Google Scholar]
1
The countries used in the dataset are the following: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Chile, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg, Mexico, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, USA.
Table 1. Summary statistics.
Table 1. Summary statistics.
MeanSDMin.Max.Obs.
InvestmentDiversification20.14812.4240.00070.25099
Diversification index above median 23.1789.6649.83052.72040
Diversification index below median 21.0987.4395.96036.95038
Dwellings22.0927.8688.31657.88382
Other building30.8998.56816.72065.27683
Transports8.7682.8474.53321.38580
Other machinery10.4193.1901.92419.82551
Cultivated assets0.5660.893−0.1505.19665
Intellectual12.3625.8721.48127.71279
CultureCultural index13.94112.067−0.04449.89591
Cultural index above median 19.37910.60310.31049.90040
Cultural index below median 5.5552.908−0.04011.15038
Trust3.4901.4050.8847.01686
Control6.9280.5955.0808.01284
Work ethic −0.0691.023−2.1881.93286
Obedience−0.2401.019−2.3441.58186
Competition−0.0790.907−1.9662.74267
Honesty−0.0211.213−5.4411.77086
Propensity to save0.3290.1130.0940.63486
Control variablesgov2.9470.2062.4313.29053
qog0.8310.1530.4761.00091
conf0.1871.056−1.8954.49567
Note: gov—the level of government expenditures; debt—government debt; inf—inflation; qog—institutional quality; conf—confidence in national institutions; Obs. —number of observations; “median” refers to the median of the cultural index.
Table 2. Correlations between cultural index and diversification index.
Table 2. Correlations between cultural index and diversification index.
Decade 1Decade 2Decade 3
Diversification (countries above median in cultural index)Diversification (countries below median in cultural index)Diversification (countries above median in cultural index)Diversification (countries below median in cultural index)Diversification (countries above median in cultural index)Diversification (countries below median in cultural index)
Above median † cultural index0.140 0.121 0.118
Below median † cultural index −0.070 0.429 0.276
Note: † “median” refers to the median of the cultural index.
Table 3. Dependent variable: Diversification index.
Table 3. Dependent variable: Diversification index.
Cultural indexCult. index above†Cult. index below†govqogconfObs.R2F
(1)Diversification−0.117
(0.132)
880.0622.95 *
(2)Div. index above −0.046
(0.101)
400.0030.48
(3)Div. index below 0.858 **
(0.409)
380.2055.21 **
(4)Div. index below 2.582 ***
(0.242)
−31.205 *
(11.250)
110.55 **
(20.531)
6.929 **
(2.091)
210.21025.70 **
Notes: standard errors in parentheses; * and ** denote significance at the 10% and 5% significance levels, respectively; all estimations were carried out using the fixed effects method allowing for both country- and decade-specific effects with robust standard errors; gov—the level of government expenditures; qog—institutional quality; conf—confidence in national institutions; Obs. —number of observations; “above” and “below” refer to above and below the median of the cultural index, respectively.