Journal of Business Accounting and Finance Perspectives

(ISSN: 2603-7475) Open Access Journal
Rss Feed:

Journal of Business Accounting and Finance Perspectives is no longer published on JAMS (the publishing platform provided by MDPI) as of 10.07.2021. The articles published until that date are archived at jbafp.archive.jams.pub by courtesy of JAMS.

J_Bus_Account_Financ_Perspect 2021, 3(1), 3; doi:10.35995/jbafp3010003

 
Culture, Institutions and Financial Development
Kyriaki I. Kafka
Department of Economics, National and Kapodistrian University of Athens, Stadiou 5 Street, 10561 Athens, Greece; kkafka@econ.uoa.gr
How to cite: Kyriaki I. Kafka. Culture, Institutions and Financial Development. J. Bus. Account. Financ. Perspect., 2021, 3(1): 3; doi:10.35995/jbafp3010003.
Received: 13 January 2021 / Accepted: 18 February 2021 / Published: 8 March 2021

Abstract

:
When culture and institutions coevolve, which means that these are changing simultaneously and in the same direction, financial development is facilitated. In contrast, when institutions and the cultural background deviate from this development, their asynchronous and different direction changes may lead to a series of failed attempts to implement a modernized financial development framework. Thus, the purpose of the paper is to highlight whether the institutional and cultural backgrounds operate in a complementary or substitute way in terms of their role in financial development. An unbalanced panel dataset comprising 98 countries over the last four decades (1981–2019) is used. The empirical results indicate that both the institutional background and the cultural background positively affect financial development. Furthermore, there is a complementary relationship between the institutional background and the cultural background in terms of their role in financial development; when both sizes are at a strong level, this leads to the highest level of financial development, while when at least one or both are at a weak level, the financial development is lower. Moreover, the interaction term of the two sizes has a positive and statistically significant effect on financial development in all tests performed. Lastly, the institutional background seems to have a greater impact on the formation of the level of financial development in relation to the cultural background. To upgrade the financial development of their economies, policymakers have to realize economic policies that change the institutional background and simultaneously change the cultural background in the same direction.
Keywords:
cultural background; institutions; financial development; coevolution

1. Introduction

The creation and structure of institutions and therefore economic outcomes are affected by all the values and beliefs of individuals as well as the views that the individual has formed during their lifetime. Economic outcomes and institutions in turn can influence the way individuals act, think and make decisions, thus generally influencing their cultural background. The cultural background—in this sense—as an informal institution is a component of the broader concept of institutions (North, 1990).
At the same time, the prevailing view is that the cultural background and institutions interact and evolve (Petrakis and Kostis, 2014; Petrakis et al., 2017; Kafka et al., 2020) complementary and reciprocal feedback (Alesina and Giuliano, 2015). In this sense, the same institutions can operate differently depending on the cultural background in which they will be applied. The cultural background in turn can change depending on the institutional background (Alesina and Giuliano, 2015).
The evolution of institutions and the cultural background does not always present a course of simultaneous development in time and in the same direction, a fact that has significant implications for economies. In other words, institutions may change in the same direction as the cultural background, but these changes may not be compatible with the time at which the end result comes.
The literature on the issue of the coevolution of the cultural background and institutions has focused, in recent years, on the natural selection that takes place in both genes and institutions, and which is thought to lead to the coevolution of these two concepts (Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman, 1981; Durham, 1992; Feldman and Zhivotovsky, 1992; Soltis et al., 1995; Boyd and Richerson, 2002; Bowles et al., 2003; Bowles, 2006; Choi and Bowles, 2007; Gintis, 2007). Some institutions and behaviors may offer an individual or individuals a competitive advantage in their work of action (Lewis and Steinmo, 2012).
In general, however, there may be an incompatibility in the evolution of the institutional and cultural background which is expressed either because (Kafka et al., 2020) (a) the institutions change but the cultural background does not change, (b) the cultural background change but the institutions do not change respectively, (c) both the institutions and the cultural background are evolving but their stagnant balance is not characterized by the optimal complementary combination between institutions and cultural attitudes and (d) a change in institutions may be accompanied by incompatibility in cultural behaviors, and vice versa. The latter form of incompatibility is also what is characterized as the worst form of incompatibility in the course of evolution between the two concepts.
The purpose of this article is to highlight the link between institutional and cultural backgrounds and how this link affects the financial development of economies. In other words, the aim is to determine whether the institutional and cultural backgrounds function in a complementary or substitute way in terms of their role in financial development, contributing to the discussion on whether or not they are evolving. For this purpose, the effects of the institutional and cultural backgrounds on financial development are determined, individually and in combination. The analysis is based on a sample of 98 countries, over a period of four decades (1981–2019), based on the constraints posed by the data relating to the cultural background of societies.
The order of the paper is as follows: The second section presents the literature review on the effects of institutions and culture on financial development. In the third section, the data and methodology used are described, and in the fourth section, the empirical analysis and the discussion of the results are presented. Finally, in the fifth section, the conclusions of the analysis are presented.

2. Literature Review

There is a wide body of literature that examines the determinants of financial development. A great part of this literature concentrates on the effects of institutions on financial development (Claessens and Laeven, 2003; Detragiache et al., 2005; Law and Demetriades, 2006; Beck and Levine, 2008; Fernández and Tamayo, 2015), while in recent years, empirical works have emerged that examine the role of national culture on financial development (Herger et al., 2008; Dutta and Mukherjee, 2012; Klein and Klein, 2017; Ang, 2019; Ahunov and Hove, 2020).
Regarding the role of institutions, Fernández and Tamayo (2015) identify three main sources of differences in the institutional framework that cause differences in financial development: (a) the inherited legal tradition regarding the way private property rights are held in an economy; (b) the emphasis societies have placed on the development of markets; and (c) the historical development of the economies that allow for discrete changes in specific institutional arrangements.
Khan et al. (2019a, 2019b) conclude that institutional quality is a significant prerequisite to financial development either for advanced economies such as the USA or for emerging and growth-leading economies. They suggest that policymakers and researchers have to consider the importance of institutions to come up with realistic estimations and policy inputs. Moreover, Aluko and Ibrahim (2020) conclude that financial development positively affects economic growth through the institutional quality of the countries.
However, there are some institutional aspects that seem to matter more than others (Law and Azman-Saini, 2008; Gazdar and Cherif, 2014). Law and Azman-Saini (2008) suggest that the rule of law, the political stability and government effectiveness play a vital role in influencing banking sector development and that regulatory quality does contribute to financial development but only when a threshold level of regulatory quality development has been attained. Gazdar and Cherif (2014) show that in Middle East and North Africa (MENA) countries, over the period of 1984–2007, law and order are the most relevant determinants of banking sector development, while corruption and investment profiles are of secondary importance. They also point out that investment profiles are the most relevant determinant of stock market development and liquidity.
Legal institutions seem to play a critical role in financial development. Beck and Levine (2008) state that in countries where legal systems enforce private property rights, support private contractual arrangements and protect the legal right of investors, savers are more willing to finance firms and financial development is achieved.
There is also literature that examines the role of political institutions on financial development (Haber, 2007; Huang, 2010; Marcelin and Mathur, 2014). Haber (2007) points out that democracy and authoritarianism play crucial roles in the incentives of bankers and political entrepreneurs. Huang (2010) points out that a democratic transformation is typically followed by an increase in financial development, while concluding in a positive effect of institutional improvement on financial development at least in the short run. Moreover, Marcelin and Mathur (2014) suggest how to get around some institutional attributes to spearhead financial intermediation and economic growth through a set of institutional and banking reforms.
Regarding the role of culture on financial development, Stulz and Williamson (2003) stress that differences in culture are critical for the level of financial development. Dutta and Mukherjee (2012) state that while culture evolves in the form of greater trust, control and other traits, individuals’ attitudes towards the financial market change, and they engage in greater financial transactions and better financial development. Herger et al. (2008) suggest that there is only limited evidence that cultural beliefs significantly hamper financial development.
Ang (2019) concentrates on the cultural value of individualism, noting that higher levels of individualism lead to a higher level of financial development. Klein and Klein (2017) conclude that higher control of life can modify transaction costs, which in turn leads to different levels of financial development. Ahunov and Hove (2020) point out that financial literacy is lower in countries where the power distance and uncertainty avoidance are high, and individualism is lower. For masculinity, indulgence and long-term orientation, they find no significant impact.
In addition, there are limited works that examine the role of institutions and culture on financial development simultaneously. Mukherjee and Dutta (2013) investigate the role of political institutions and culture in creating an efficient financial infrastructure for a country. They show that both political institutions and culture jointly promote financial development while behaving as complements. Moreover, Khan et al. (2019b) find that national culture significantly moderates financial development through their positive interaction with institutional quality.

3. Methodology and Data

In order for the present article to examine the relationship between the substitution or complementarity of the cultural and institutional backgrounds, the link between each variable and financial development is initially sought. Later, their simultaneous effect on financial development is examined in order to highlight the relationship of complementarity or substitution. The data for the financial development come from the Financial Development Index of the International Monetary Fund (IMF). These data are converted from annual to average for each wave of analysis (1981–1984, 1990–1994, 1995–1998, 1999–2004, 2005–2009, 2010–2014, 2017–2019)1.
To measure the cultural background, a comprehensive measure was used which emerges as the first principal component of a principal component analysis (PCA) series of cultural values of societies. The cultural values that make up the cultural background are trust, control of life, respect, independence, honesty, competition affinity and work ethic. The variables honesty, acceptance of competition and work ethic resulted from individual principal component analysis (PCA) using selected variables from the World Values Survey (WVS) and the European Values Study (EVS) to express each variable. The first major component for the overall measurement of the cultural background follows a normalization on a scale of 0 to 10 (according to Williamson and Mathers, 2011), with 0 indicating a weak cultural background and 10 a strong cultural background2.
The way the various cultural values were calculated was based on other empirical works in the relevant literature: generalized trust (Inglehart, 1988; Tabellini, 2008, 2010; Bützer et al., 2013; Kostis et al., 2018), respect (Tabellini, 2008, 2010), independence and control of life (Tabellini, 2008, 2010; Bützer et al., 2013; Kostis et al., 2018) and honesty, competition affinity and work ethic (Bützer et al., 2013; Kostis et al., 2018).
To measure the institutional background, the Economic Freedom of the World Index was used, an indicator generated by the Fraser Institute (Gwartney et al., 2019). The construction of the index is based on 42 sub-indices and is set on a scale from 0 to 10, with 10 representing the best performance. Despite the availability of alternative indicators to express the institutional background of economies (such as the Heritage Foundation’s Economic Freedom Index and the protection against the risk of expropriation by the ICRG), the Fraser Institute’s index was used as the most appropriate due to its long history and because of the size of the sample of countries covered by this index.
For the empirical documentation of the objectives of the chapter, an unbalanced panel dataset comprising 98 countries was used. The time period of the analysis concerns the period 1981–2019. Due to restrictions on the availability of data that make up the variable cultural background as well as the fact that these data are available in waves of more than one year, the analysis was based on seven (7) total waves. Six (6) of these waves come from WVS and are 1981–1984, 1990–1994, 1995–1998, 1999–2004, 2005–2009 and 2010–2014. For the period 2017–2019, the data were obtained from EVS (2nd publication of data, July 2019). In addition, data from EVS (EVS 1981, 1990, 1999, 2008) complement the country sample in the remaining 6 WVS waves.
In order to assess the relationship between cultural and institutional backgrounds separately in financial development as well as their relationship to each other (substitute or complementary), the following assessment, Equation (1), was performed.
Note that Equation (1) is substandard for the analysis, as for the clarification of the relationships, the following were estimated: (a) the effect of the cultural background and (b) the institutional background separately on financial development, (c) the effect of both variables simultaneously on the dependent variable, (d) the effect of their product and (e) their ratio, separately, on the dependent variable. The product of the two concepts was used as a control measure of their complementarity in the sense that the higher their product, the larger the two sizes, while the smaller their product, the lower the values of the two variables.
Financial Developmentit = αi + β1 * Culturet + β2 * Institutionsit + γ * Χit + δ * Ζit + λt + uit
where i represents each economy of the sample under analysis (Nmax = 113) and t represents the corresponding wave (Tmax = 7). The dependent variable Financial Development refers to the Financial Development Index. The variables Culture and Institutions are the variables that express the cultural and institutional backgrounds of societies, respectively, the variable X represents the product or the ratio of the two concepts, Z is a vector of control variables, ai is a constant term that represents some country-specific effects in order to record the impact of unobserved and timeless heterogeneity in countries and λt is a dummy variable for each wave of the sample, which controls specific effects per wave that are common in all countries.
Estimates were made through fixed effects analysis (FE), which allows the specific heterogeneity per economy using a different constant term per economy and can be estimated using the ordinary least squares (OLS) method. In addition, time variables were included for each wave in order to incorporate in the analysis time effects that are common to all countries in the sample. In addition, country-specific clustered robust estimates of the standard errors were made in order to check the correlation and heteroskedasticity for each economy.
The results were subjected to a robustness check by adding control variables to the analysis. This concerned the integration of various combinations of control variables in the analysis and observation of whether the effect of the relationship between cultural and institutional backgrounds on financial development changes or not.
According to previous studies that assess the relationship between cultural and institutional backgrounds and macroeconomic outcomes (Williamson, 2009; Williamson and Mathers, 2011; Mathers and Williamson, 2011), a Z-vector that includes various control variables was also included. Regarding the control variables, the level of unemployment was used since its effects on financial development have been highly investigated in the relevant literature (Gatti and Vaubourg, 2009; Shabbir et al., 2012; Ilo, 2015; Ogbeide et al., 2015; Bayar, 2016). Public debt was also used as a control variable for financial development (Hauner, 2009; Ismihan and Ozkan, 2012; İlgün, 2016). Moreover, the size of agricultural lands on financial development was used (Byamugisha, 1999; Yazdi and Khanalizadeh, 2014; Cagliarini and Rush, 2011).
Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics for the variables included in the analysis.

4. Empirical Results and Discussion

In order to create the variability of honesty, competition affinity, work ethic and cultural background, the PCA was followed. In each analysis performed, the first principal component was obtained.
More specifically, from the analysis of the main components for the variable “honesty”, the first component has an eigenvalue value of 1.751 and interprets 87.60% of the variation. The two sub-variables have a positive effect and form the variable “honesty”. From the PCA for the variable “competition affinity”, the first component has an eigenvalue of 1.263 and interprets 63.16% of the variation. Therefore, the variable “competition affinity” is positively shaped by both sub-variables. From the PCA for the variable “work ethic”, the first component has an eigenvalue value of 1.068 and interprets 53.14% of the variance. The variable “work ethic” is positively shaped by both sub-variables. Based on the above variables, Table 2 presents the PCA for the variable cultural background. As mentioned, this variable was derived from a PCA based on the following variables: trust, control of life, respect, independence, honesty, competition affinity and work ethic.
From the PCA for the variable “cultural background”, the first component has an eigenvalue value of 2.463 and interprets 35.20% of the variation. All the following components, apart from the first one, have quite low eigenvalues and fluctuation values, and for this reason, they are not used in the analysis. Thus, the changing “cultural background” is shaped positively by trust, respect and independence, while it is shaped in a negative way by competition affinity and work ethic (the variables life control and honesty do not seem to play an important role in shaping the first principal component) (Table 2).
In order to assess the effect of the cultural background and the institutional background separately on the GDP per capita, the effect of both variables simultaneously and their product and ratio separately on the GDP per capita, Equation (1) is evaluated for the panel data, of the group of 98 countries, for the seven waves from 1981 to 2019.
The results are shown in Table 3, where the results of the equation estimation (1) are presented without the use of control variables.
The regression data (1) demonstrate the positive and statistically significant effect of the institutional background on financial development, as observed for culture in regression (2) as well. Regression (3) combines the institutional and cultural backgrounds to explore the relationship of the substitution or complementarity of both sizes in terms of how they affect financial development. The simultaneous relationship between the institutional and the cultural background is positive and statistically significant for both sizes. The results of regression (3) support the hypothesis of the complementarity of the two concepts.
In regressions (4), (5) and (6), the interaction term (Williamson 2009) of the two variables is introduced, where in regression (4), it concerns the product of the institutional and cultural backgrounds, while in regressions (5) and (6), it is introduced in their ratio (by alternating the two sizes between the numerator and denominator). Regression (4) confirms the complementary relationship of the two variables as their occurrence has a positive and statistically significant effect on financial development. As the product of the institutional and cultural backgrounds increases (the stronger the two sizes become at the same time), a higher level of financial development is expected. On the contrary, when this product is reduced (the weaker the two sizes at the same time), lower financial development is expected. Regressions (5) and (6) reinforce the conclusions of regression (3) regarding the importance of the institutional background on financial development. In both cases, the role of the institutional background is more important than that of the cultural background in shaping financial development.
The above conclusions empower the complementary relationship between the two variables on the financial development of the countries as well as the particularly great importance of the institutional background on the level of financial development of the economies.
The above results were subject to robustness analysis with the addition of control variables to the analysis (regressions 7 to 12). The conclusion that the institutional and cultural backgrounds have both a positive and a statistically significant relationship with financial development remains, while at the same time, in all cases, it appears that the impact of the institutional background is greater than that of the cultural background.

5. Conclusions

The previous analysis shows the complementary relationship between the institutional and the cultural background regarding their role in financial development, as when both sizes are at a strong level, this leads to the highest level of economic development. When at least one or both are at a weak level, financial development is lower.
In addition, the interaction of the two sizes (product) has a positive and statistically significant effect on financial development in all controls performed, and this is another indication of the complementarity of the two sizes.
The requirements for the coevolution of the institutional and cultural backgrounds are critical for the financial development of an economy. When institutions and the cultural background evolve simultaneously and in the same direction, the process of financial development is facilitated. Conversely, when institutions and the cultural background deviate from coevolution, their asynchronous or different orientation may result in the inability of policymakers to implement the required changes in the institutional and/or cultural backgrounds. The result can be a series of failed attempts to implement a modernized development framework for the institutional and cultural backgrounds of societies, leading to the perpetuation of a low financial development.
Thus, the existence of economic freedom (sufficient size of state, existence of rule of law, access to strong currency, freedom in international trade and satisfactory regulatory environment in bank credit, labor and entrepreneurship) is an important condition for economies. However, when these conditions are accompanied by social behaviors that promote financial development and are related to the trust and independence of individuals (high level of generalized trust, respect and independence), the highest possible level of financial development is achieved.
Of course, satisfactory planning and implementation of policies that will strengthen the institutional background are very difficult in practice. It is also very difficult for the rulers to have the knowledge and also the necessary incentives to choose appropriate institutions to promote financial development. The position that institutional structures are easily recognizable and that an economy can copy the successful institutional framework of another economy should be carefully considered (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2012). The reason for the failures of planning a strong institutional background is that the efficiency of economic policy and the institutional background is significantly affected by the current cultural values of societies and how ready societies are to accept the changes that accompany these policies.
The analysis of this article presents some disadvantages. Although all available data were used to express the cultural background of societies (from the first to the last wave of WVS and EVS (July 2019), there are several economies that participated in the relevant research only in some of these waves. In addition, the measure used for the institutional background (the indicator of economic freedom) best describes the economic institutions of economies and does not examine the political and social institutions of societies.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D.; Robinson, J. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty; Crown: New York, NY, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  2. Alesina, A.; Giuliano, P. Culture and Institutions. Journal of Economic Literature 2015, 53(4), 898–944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Ahunov, M.; Hove, L. V. National culture and financial literacy: International evidence. Applied Economics 2020, 52(21), 2261–2279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Aluko, O. A.; Ibrahim, M. Institutions and the financial development-economic growth nexus in sub-Saharan Africa. Economic Notes 2020, 49(3), e12163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ang, J. B. Culture, Legal Origins and Financial Development. Economic Inquiry 2019, 57(2), 1016–1037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Beck, T.; Levine, R. Legal Institutions and Financial Development. In Handbook of New Institutional Economics; Ménard, C., Shirley, M. M., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  7. Bowles, S. Group competition, reproductive leveling, and the evolution of human altruism. Science 2006, 314(5805), 1569–1572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  8. Bowles, S.; Choi, J. K.; Hopfensitz, A. The co-evolution of individual behaviors and social institutions. Journal of Theoretical Biology 2003, 223(2), 135–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Boyd, R.; Richerson, P. J. Group beneficial norms can spread rapidly in a structured population. Journal of Theoretical Biology 2002, 215(3), 287–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  10. Bützer, S.; Jordan, C.; Stracca, L. Macroeconomic Imbalances: A Question of Trust? (Working Paper 1584); European Central Bank, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  11. Byamugisha, F. F. K. The Effect of Land Registration on Financial Development and Economic Growth; (Policy Research Working Paper 2240); World Bank, 1999. [Google Scholar]
  12. Cagliarini, A.; Rush, A. Economic Development and Agriculture in India; (Bulletin—June Quarter); Reserve Bank of Australia, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  13. Cavalli-Sforza, L. L.; Feldman, M. W. Cultural Transmission and Evolution: A Quantitative Approach; Princeton University Press: Princeton, 1981. [Google Scholar]
  14. Choi, J. K.; Bowles, S. The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science 2007, 318(5850), 636–640. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Claessens, S.; Laeven, L. Financial Development, Property Rights, and Growth. The Journal of Finance 2003, 58(6), 2401–2436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Detragiache, E.; Gupta, P.; Tressel, T. Finance in Lower Income Countries: An Empirical Exploration; (IMF Working Paper No. 05/167); International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  17. Durham, W. H. Coevolution: Genes, Culture, and Human Diversity; Stanford University Press: Stanford, 1992. [Google Scholar]
  18. Dutta, N.; Mukherjee, D. Is Culture a Determinant of Financial Development? Applied Economics Letters 2012, 19(6), 585–590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Feldman, M. W.; Zhivotovsky, L. A. Gene-culture coevolution: Toward a general theory of vertical transmission. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 1992, 89(24), 11935–11938. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Fernández, A.; Tamayo, C. E. From Institutions To Financial Development And Growth: What Are The Links? Journal of Economic Surveys 2015, 31(1), 17–57. [Google Scholar]
  21. Gatti, D.; Vaubourg, A. G. Unemployment and Finance: How Do Financial and Labour Market Factors Interact? (IZA Discussion Paper); 2009; http://ftp.iza.org/dp4075.pdf.
  22. Gazdar, K.; Cherif, M. The quality of institutions and financial development in mena countries: An empirical investigation. Risk Governance & Control: Financial Markets & Institutions 2014, 4(4-1), 65–80. [Google Scholar]
  23. Gintis, H. A framework for the unification of the behavioral sciences. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 2007, 30(1), 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Gwartney, J.; Lawson, R.; Hall, J. Economic Freedom of the World: 2019 Annual Report; Fraser Insitute, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  25. Haber, S. Political Institutions and Financial Development: Evidence from New World Economies; (EUI MWP LS 2007/10); European University Institute, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  26. Hauner, C. Public debt and financial development. Journal of Development Economics 2009, 88(1), 171–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Herger, N.; Hodler, R.; Lobsiger, M. What Determines Financial Development? Culture, Institutions or Trade. Review of World Economics 2008, 144, 558–587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Huang, Y. Political Institutions and Financial Development: An Empirical Study. World Development 2010, 38(12), 1667–1677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Ilo, B. M. Capital market and unemployment in Nigeria. Oeconomica 2015, 11(5), 129–140. [Google Scholar]
  30. İlgün, M. F. Financial Development and Domestic Public Debt in Emerging Economies: A Panel Cointegration Analysis. Journal of Applied Economics and Business Research 2016, 6(4), 284–296. [Google Scholar]
  31. Inglehart, R. The Renaissance of Political Culture. American Political Science Review 1988, 82, 1028–1034. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Ismihan, M.; Ozkan, O. G. Public debt and financial development: A theoretical exploration. Economics Letters 2012, 115(3), 348–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Kafka, K. I.; Kostis, P. C.; Petrakis, P. E. Why Coevolution of Culture and Institutions Matters for Economic Development and Growth? In Economic-Financial Development and Cultural Transformation; Yonk, R. M., Ed.; IntecOpen, 2020; ISBN 978-1-78985-938-6. [Google Scholar]
  34. Khan, M. A.; Kong, D.; Xiang, J.; Zhang, J. Impact of Institutional Quality on Financial Development: Cross-Country Evidence based on Emerging and Growth-Leading Economies. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 2019a, 56(15), 3829–3845. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Khan, M. A.; Khan, M. A.; Abdulahi, M. E.; Liaqat, I.; Shah, S. S. H. Institutional quality and financial development: The United States perspective. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 2019b, 49, 67–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Klein, A.; Klein, R. F. Communism, Culture, and Financial Development. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues 2017, 7, 575–589. [Google Scholar]
  37. Kostis, P. C.; Kafka, K. I.; Petrakis, P. E. Cultural Change and Innovation Performance. Journal of Business Research 2018, 88, 306–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Law, S. H.; Azman-Saini, W. N. W. The Quality of Institutions and Financial Development; (MPRA Working Paper 12107); Munich Personal RePEc Archive, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  39. Law, S. H.; Demetriades, P. O. Openness, Institutions and Financial Development; (WEFRP Working Paper No. WEF 0012); SSRN, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  40. Lewis, O.; Steinmo, S. How Institutions Evolve: Evolutionary Theory and Institutional Change. Polity 2012, 44(3), 314–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Marcelin, I.; Mathur, I. Financial development, institutions and banks. International Review of Financial Analysis 2014, 31, 25–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Mathers, R. L.; Williamson, C. R. Cultural Context: Explaining the Productivity of Capitalism. Kyklos 2011, 64(2), 231–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Mukherjee, D.; Dutta, N. Do Political Institutions and Culture Jointly Matter for Financial Development? A Cross-Country Panel Investigation. Global Economy Journal 2013, 13(2), 203–232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. North, D. C. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance; Cambridge University Press, 1990. [Google Scholar]
  45. Ogbeide, F. I.; Kanwanye, H.; Kadiri, S. The determinants of unemployment and the question of inclusive growth in Nigeria: Do resource dependence, government expenditure and financial development matter? Montenegrin Journal of Economics 2015, 11(2), 49–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Petrakis, P. E.; Kostis, P. C. Medium Term Effects of Culture, Transactions and Institutions on Opportunity Entrepreneurship. Journal of Innovation and Entrepreneurship 2014, 3(1), 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Petrakis, P. E.; Valsamis, D. G.; Kafka, K. I. From an Optimal to a Stagnated Growth Prototype: The Role of Institutions and Culture. Journal of Innovation & Knowledge 2017, 2(3), 97–105. [Google Scholar]
  48. Shabbir, G.; Anwar, S.; Hussain, Z.; Imran, M. Contribution of financial sector development in reducing unemployment in Pakistan. International Journal of Economics and Finance 2012, 4(1), 260–268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Soltis, J.; Boyd, R.; Richerson, P. J. Can group-function al behaviors evolve by cultural group selection? An empirical test. Current Anthropology 1995, 36(3), 473–494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Stulz, R. M.; Williamson, R. Culturem Openess and Finance. Journal of Financial Economics 2003, 70(3), 313–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Tabellini, G. The Scope of Cooperation: Values and Incentives. Quarterly Journal of Economics 2008, 123(3), 905–950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Tabellini, G. Culture and Institutions: Economic Development in the Regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association 2010, 8(4), 677–716. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Williamson, C. R. Informal Institutions Rule: Institutional Arrangements and Economic Performance. Public Choice 2009, 139(3), 371–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Williamson, C. R.; Mathers, R. L. Economic Freedom, Culture, and Growth. Public Choice 2011, 148, 313–335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Yazdi, S. K.; Khanalizadeh, B. The Financial Development and Agriculture Growth in Iran: ARDL Approach. In Proceedings of the 5th International Conference on Development, Energy, Environment, Economics Recent Advances in Energy, Environment and Financial Planning; 2014; pp. 335–342. [Google Scholar]
  56. Bayar, Y. Financial development and unemployment in emerging market economies. Scientific Annals of Economics and Business 2016, 63(2), 237–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1
The analysis is based on these sub-waves due to the availability of cultural background data which—as described later in this section—are published by WVS and EVS in waves.
2
The 0 to 10 harmonization was conducted to make the measurement of the cultural background similar to that of the institutional background, as the institutional background used below is measured on a scale of 0 to 10.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
NAverageStandard DeviationMinMax
Financial Development6650.370.220.010.93
Institutions6106.571.242.599.12
Culture1520.001.57−4.524.58
 Trust36628.4015.632.5077.40
 Control of life35215.368.520.0043.90
 Respect35967.8713.2414.2096.30
 Independence36448.1018.797.9090.00
 Honesty3310.001.32−3.843.67
  Honesty Ι35460.0414.7320.3098.10
  Honesty ΙΙ33855.9315.5812.6096.30
 Competition affinity1780.001.12−1.736.14
  Competition affinity Ι32726.1012.323.7066.30
  Competition affinity ΙΙ1837.666.950.3077.30
 Work ethic3350.001.03−2.732.43
  Work ethic Ι36252.8525.432.1094.60
  Work ethic ΙΙ33861.8214.9526.1095.10
Unemployment5398.836.120.1745.37
Debt54752.1035.100.03344.31
Agricultural Land60341.5721.321.0085.74
Table 2. “Cultural background” formation.
Table 2. “Cultural background” formation.
Trust0.466
Control of life−0.226
Respect0.325
Independence0.389
Honesty0.027
Competition affinity−0.457
Work ethic−0.507
Eigenvalue2.463
Variance35.2%
Table 3. The impact of the institutional and cultural background on the financial development of countries.
Table 3. The impact of the institutional and cultural background on the financial development of countries.
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)(11)(12)
Institutional background0.06 ***
(7.11)
0.06 ***
(4.65)
0.07 ***
(5.88)
0.04 ***
(2.68)
Cultural background 0.06 ***
(3.65)
0.04 ***
(2.51)
0.04 ***
(2.24)
0.03 *
(1.66)
Institutions * Culture 0.01 ***
(5.46)
0.01 ***
(2.92)
Institutions/Culture 0.07 *
(2.40)
0.04
(0.80)
Culture/Institutions −0.14 ***
(−2.66)
−0.02
(−0.34)
Unemployment −0.01 ***
(−4.26)
−0.02 ***
(−3.03)
−0.01 ***
(−3.94)
−0.01 ***
(−3.37)
−0.01 ***
(4.25)
−0.02 ***
(−3.83)
Debt 0.01 ***
(4.29)
0.01 ***
(4.60)
0.01 ***
(4.49)
0.01 ***
(4.62)
0.01 ***
(4.25)
0.01 ***
(4.23)
Agricultural land −0.01 ***
(−3.03)
−0.02 ***
(−3.10)
−0.02 ***
(−2.69)
−0.02 ***
(−2.74)
−0.02 ***
(−3.66)
−0.02 ***
(−3.68)
Ν585140129129128129321103101101101101
R241.35%32.84%49.42%46.27%3.36%4.07%39.73%50.72%57.41%56.90%43.88%43.45%
F-stat50.62 ***13.34 ***14.42 ***29.78 ***5.76 ***7.08 ***13.53 ***9.48 ***9.91 ***11.87 ***9.33 ***9.00 ***
Notes: The t-statistics values are displayed in parentheses. *, ** and *** represent statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1% significance levels, respectively. Each column represents a separate regression. All regressions have included the effect of the time variable (taking into account the effects common to countries in each wave), different constant terms (to take into account the effects on each economy separately) and corrections to standard errors (clustered robust standard errors).